BEIJING – China’s
12th Five-Year Plan calls for a shift in the country’s economic model from
export-led growth toward greater reliance on domestic demand, particularly
household consumption. Since the Plan’s introduction, China’s
current-account surplus as a share of GDP has indeed fallen. But does that mean
that China’s
adjustment is on track?
The IMF’s explanation of the recent
fall in China’s
current-account surplus/GDP ratio is broadly correct. Experience suggests that China’s
external position is highly sensitive to global conditions, with the
surplus/GDP ratio rising during boom times for the world economy and falling
during slumps. Europe’s malaise has hit China’s
exports badly, and undoubtedly is the most important factor underlying the
current decline in the ratio.
By definition, without a change in the
saving gap, there will be no change in the trade surplus, and vice versa.
Furthermore, the saving gap and the trade balance interact with each other
constantly, making them always equal. In response to the global financial
crisis in 2008, China
introduced a RMB4 trillion ($634 billion) stimulus package. While the increase
in investment reduced the saving/GDP ratio, the resulting increase in imports
lowered the trade surplus/GDP ratio. As a result, China’s
external surplus/GDP ratio fell significantly in 2009.
In 2010, China’s government adjusted its economic policy. In order to control inflation and real-estate bubbles, the central bank tightened monetary policy and the government refrained from another round of fiscal stimulus. China’s real-estate investment accounted for 10% of GDP, and slower investment growth in the sector necessarily reduces import demand, directly and indirectly. But, because the fall in import growth had yet to turn into a rout, while China’s exports to Europe plummeted, China’s current-account surplus fell further in GDP terms in 2011.
This situation is likely to change in
2012. The negative impact of the fall in real-estate investment since 2010 has
been deeper and longer than expected; indeed, almost all categories of imports
that fell by 10% or more in August were related to real-estate investment. As a
result, it is possible that the fall in investment growth will reverse the
declining external surplus/GDP ratio in 2012, unless the global economy
deteriorates further and/or the Chinese government launches a new stimulus
package.
Perhaps most important, China
must now export more manufactured goods to finance imports of energy and
mineral products. The worsening terms of trade have been a major factor
contributing to the decline in the current-account surplus in recent years.
Nevertheless, despite the merits of
its analysis, the IMF underestimates China’s
progress in rebalancing. In my view, China’s
rebalancing is more genuine – and more fundamental – than the Fund recognizes,
and the prediction of an eventual rebound in China’s
external surplus/GDP ratio will most likely turn out to be wrong.
First, the roughly 30% real
exchange-rate appreciation since 2005 must have had a serious impact on
exporters, reflected in the bankruptcy – as well as the upgrading – of many
enterprises in coastal areas. Though the market shares of Chinese exports seem
to have held up quite well, this is attributable to price-cutting in foreign
markets, which is not sustainable. Over time, real exchange-rate appreciation
will cause a shift in expenditure, making China’s
rebalancing more apparent.
Second, China’s
wage levels are rising rapidly. According to the 12th Five-Year Plan, the
minimum wage should grow by 13% per year. Together with real appreciation, the
increase in labor costs is bound to weaken the competitiveness of China’s
labor-intensive export sector, which will be reflected in the trade balance
more clearly in the coming years.
Third, China
has made significant progress in building its social-security system. The
number of people covered by basic old-age insurance, unemployment insurance,
workers’ compensation, and maternity insurance has risen substantially.
Moreover, universal medical insurance is emerging, and a comprehensive system
for providing aid to students from poor families has been established. As a
result, the motivation for precautionary saving has been weakened somewhat,
while some researchers have found statistical evidence that the consumption
rate is rising, which is supported by China’s
emergence as the world’s fourth-largest importer of luxury goods.
Finally, the worsening of China’s
terms of trade will play an even more fundamental role in reducing its trade
surplus in the future. Given weak demand, which may be prolonged, Chinese
exporters must accept increasingly thin profit margins to maintain market
share. However, China’s
large size and low per capita income and capital stock imply continued
rapid growth in its demand for commodities. Thanks to supply constraints, China’s
import bill for commodities and metals is likely to offset its processing-trade
surplus in the near future.
In short, as long as China’s government is not so unnerved by the slowdown in output growth that it changes its current policy stance, the current-account surplus is more likely to continue to fall relative to GDP than it is to rebound in 2013 and thereafter. In fact, such an outcome is not only likely, but also desirable. After all, faced with “infinite quantitative easing,” being a large net creditor means being in the worst position in today’s global economy.