Excerpt from China’s Trapped Transition - The Limits of
Developmental Autocracy by Minxin Pei
Growing
Imbalances in Society and Polity
The idea that
severe structural imbalances have accumulated in China’s society and political
system has gained currency within China.59 Specifically, such
imbalances refer to the rising inequality (socioeconomic, regional, and urban-rural),
the growing tensions between the ruling elite and the masses, the erosion of
values, and the simultaneous consolidation of an elite-based exclusivist ruling
coalition and the increasing marginalization of weak groups, such as workers,
peasants, and migrant laborers.60 Because of these imbalances, some
Chinese social scientists warn that enormous risks have built up in Chinese
society. Citing rising public dissatisfaction, growing unemployment, and
increasing inequality, Wang Shaoguang, Hu Angang, and Ding Yuanzhu argue that
China has entered a new period of social instability. 61 Sun Liping,
a sociologist, has identified such imbalances as contributing to destabilizing
social divisions in Chinese society.62 Unavoidably, such imbalances
are reflected in rising tensions in state-society relations. Both
aggregate-level data and press reports indicate a sharp rise in the number of
incidents of collective protests, violent confrontations, and various forms of
defiance and resistance against state authorities.63
Obviously, as
expressions of social discontent, such acts of protest are likely the product
of the hardships suffered by groups hurt by economic transition, such as
peasants and urban SOE workers. (Indeed, protests from these two social groups
account for the majority of collective riots.) The rising frequency, scale, and
intensity of collective protest and individual resistance also reveal the flaws
in the Chinese political institutions that give rise to the buildup of such
stress during transition. The breakdown of the system of political
accountability governing agents of the state is likely one of the key causes of
rising state-society tensions in the Chinese context. State agents who
routinely abuse their power and perpetrate acts of petty despotism create
victims every day, personify state predation, and bring ordinary citizens into
direct contact with state oppression. Private grievances accumulated in such a
system are more likely to find violent expressions when institutional
mechanisms for resolving them—such as the courts, the press, and government
bureaucracies—are unresponsive, inadequate, or dysfunctional.
Additionally, the
CCP’s resistance to democratic reforms results in the lack of effective
channels for political participation and interest representation, creating an
environment in which groups unable to defend their interests are forced to take
high-risk options of collective protest to voice their demands and hope for
compensatory policies. The totality of such institutional flaws contributes to
a systemic propensity toward violent collective protests even in the absence of
organized social interests.64 The accumulation and increase of
state-society tensions bode ill for political stability in China, especially
because the dynamics that generate such tensions trap the ruling CCP in an
almost hopeless dilemma. As the CCP’s initial resistance to political reform
has aggravated state-society tensions, rising tensions increase the risks that
any such reform could get out of control, thus deterring the CCP from
undertaking it. This political paralysis further fuels state-society tensions as
individual and collective grievances continue to accumulate, compounding risks
of future reform.
These difficult
challenges and deeply embedded structural problems in China’s closed political
system and partially reformed economy further cast into doubt whether China can
sustain its dynamic economic modernization. To address this question in this
book, I will first explore, at the theoretical level, the causes and dynamics
of a trapped transition. The theoretical framework developed will then guide
the four empirical chapters that examine the pathologies created by partial
political and economic reforms in China.
......
ONE
Why
Transitions Get Trapped: A Theoretical Framework
IN PROBING the
underlying causes and dynamics that have contributed to the emergence of a
partial reform equilibrium that exhibits, metaphorically speaking, the distinct
characteristics of a trapped transition, we now turn to three sets of
theoretical literature: democratization, economic reform, and the state. By
applying the theoretical insights from the literature, we can better understand
the logic of trapped transitions and the political and institutional mechanisms
through which market and political transitions under autocratic rule lose
momentum and direction.
Economic
Development and Political Change
Most studies of
the impact of economic development on political change suggest a robust link
between rising levels of economic well-being and the openness of the political
system, and between changing social structures and the emergence of political
competition.1 Historical examples of democratization and more recent
cases of democratic transition in several fast-growing East Asian societies
(South Korea, Taiwan, and Thailand) further bolster the hope that China could
follow a similar evolutionary path toward political openness. The absence of
substantive movement toward such openness in China—even after twenty-five years
of economic reform that have produced one of the economic miracles in
history—does not necessarily negate the key theoretical assumptions of the
relationship between economic development and democracy. For one, China’s rapid
economic growth started on a relatively low base. The per capita GDP was US$151
in 1978 and US$769 in 1999, based on the exchange rate. It is likely that
despite more than two decades of sustained high growth, China’s economic
development may not have reached a level sufficiently high enough for
democratic transition to occur. This makes China lie outside the “democratic
transition zone” hypothesized by Samuel Huntington, who found that
non-democratic countries with per capita GDP of US$1,000 to $3,000 were more
likely to liberalize or democratize.2
Judging by per capita GDP on a purchasing power parity basis, however, China
may have entered the transition zone in the late 1980s.3
In addition,
several factors unique to China may also explain why a movement toward
democratic transition has failed to materialize. China’s huge size and enormous
regional disparities in economic development constitute an extra hurdle because
the growth of social forces, considered essential for the emergence of
democracy, is uneven across regions. The costs of organizing and coordinating
countrywide collective action can be prohibitive, especially in the context of
authoritarian repression and underdeveloped communications infrastructure. The
institutions, practices, and collective mentality of China’s quasi-totalitarian
regime pose another, and definitely tougher, obstacle to progress toward
democracy. In all former communist countries, transition toward democracy has
occurred only after a sudden breakdown of the old regime. Historically, no
communist regime has ever completed an evolutionary process of democratic
transition. This suggests that transitions from communist regimes to democracy gradually
managed by the old regime itself may be infeasible because the overwhelming
advantages possessed by the regime over potential opposition groups would give
the ruling elites no incentives to exit power, even through a negotiated
process. The growth of autonomous, organized social forces is more difficult in
such a system even when economic development may have created a large number of
individuals with middle-class socioeconomic attributes. Democratic transition
can occur most likely as a result of regime collapse because when the ruling
elites are eventually forced to undertake even limited political reforms, the
regime may have become so enfeebled by misrule and politically delegitimized
that it no longer possesses the capacity to manage a gradual opening.
The slow progress
in democratic reform in China may thus be better explained by theories of
democratic transition that focus on the political choices made by the ruling
elites as the immediate and direct causes of regime change. After all, theories
based on economic development and social structures may best explain the social
and economic contexts in which democratic institutions may emerge and function,
but are not helpful in identifying the timing and exigencies of the transition.
Proponents of the crucial role of the decisions made by the ruling elites in
the authoritarian regime maintain that democratic transitions per se have
little to do with the social structure or levels of economic development.4
Rather, such transitions take place only when the ruling elites make the
crucial decision to withdraw from power, even though the political contexts in
which such decisions are made vary from regime to regime.5 From the
perspective of choice-based theories, we may even posit a perverse short-run
negative relationship between rising levels of economic development and
democratic transition: everything else being equal, the ruling elites may have
less incentive to withdraw from power because rising prosperity makes their
political monopoly more valuable.
More important,
the authoritarian ruling elites can reap political gains from increasing
economic growth because such growth helps legitimize their rule and vindicate
their policies. Contrary to the assumption that high economic growth can create
more favorable conditions for political opening, rising prosperity can actually
remove the pressure for democratization, and frustrations with the slow speed
of economic reform may force leaders to seek political reform.6
Indeed, such appears to be the case with the Chinese experience, as the
following chapter on political reform will show. During the reform era, the
CCP’s senior leadership was most concerned about political reform only when
economic reform appeared to have stalled and growth performance was
deteriorating. This was the case with Deng’s promotion of an agenda of
political reform in 1986 when his economic reform initiatives were stymied by
bureaucracy and growth began to falter.7
A short-term
impact of rising economic prosperity on democratization also grants the ruling
elites more material resources to strengthen their repressive capacity and
co-opt potential opposition groups, especially counterelites. For example, the
CCP’s efforts to co-opt the intelligentsia and the private entrepreneurs—the
former being the leading opposition group in the 1980s and the latter a likely
challenger to the party’s power in the future—were highly successful in the
1990s mainly because the rapid growth gave the CCP the economic means of
political co-optation.
Yet, however
salutary to the autocratic regime’s rule, rising economic prosperity can
provide, at best, a short-time lift to the prospects of such regimes because of
the self-destructive political dynamics inherent in an autocracy caught up in
rapid socioeconomic change. To an extent, most ruling elites are aware that
economic development will result in the emergence of powerful challengers to
power and probably the loss of the political monopoly. Such a realization would
prompt the agents of the regime to increase their discount rate for future
income from the monopoly and, consequently, intensify their efforts to maximize
current income while maintaining a high level of repression to deter
challengers. In addition, the collapse of a foreign regime with similar
characteristics may make fears of losing one’s own power even more acute and
real. The net effects of the combination of a growing sense of long-term
insecurity and the demonstration effects of a fallen fellow autocracy may be
those akin to a run on the bank, with agents rushing to cash in their political
investments in the regime, quickening the collapse of the regime’s authority.8
Intriguingly, one
can find some evidence of a rising discount rate in the behavior of China’s
ruling elites. In Chinese press stories of officials punished for corruption,
many officials openly admit that they have lost faith in communism and in the
CCP, and that their corrupt actions were prompted by their fear of the future.
Some high-ranking officials have even resorted to superstition to help them
predict the future. Hu Changqing, a deputy governor of Jiangxi executed for
corruption, reportedly told his son (who had already immigrated to North
America) that “one day China will be no more ... But with two nationalities, we
will have insurance.” (Hu got every member of his family false identity papers
and passports.) Hu Jianxue, the party secretary of the city of Tai’an in
Shandong, privately told his subordinates that “Socialism is a dead-end.”9
Li Zhen, the head
of the provincial tax bureau in Hebei province who was executed in 2003 for
accepting tens of millions of yuan in bribes, confessed to his interrogators:
After the collapse
of the Soviet Union, many former senior Soviet officials had to work as
security guards and peddle pancakes on the street. I wrongly thought that,
rather than losing everything once the party’s power is gone, I should start
making economic preparations [accumulating wealth] when I still have power—just
to be ready for the worst.
Li’s worries were
shared by another official, a deputy county party secretary in an unnamed
province, who said:
The disintegration
of the Soviet Union at the end of 1991 made me lose my faith. I thought it was
hard to say whether the CCP could survive and avoid the same fate! Two months
later, Deng Xiaoping’s speech on his southern tour was published, I wrongly
thought that the market economy China was going to build was the same as the
free economy that followed the Soviet disintegration. Free economy means freely
grabbing money. So I used my power to grab money aggressively.10
Empirically, the
rising discount rate for future gains from membership in the ruling elite is
reflected in the corruption by younger officials. If the discount rate remains
constant, fewer younger officials will run the risk of getting caught for
corruption because they can afford to wait and, in return, will probably
receive greater total returns on their political investments. Prior to the
1990s, official corruption was frequently associated with the so-called
fifty-nine phenomenon (officials approaching the mandatory retirement age of
sixty were more tempted to break the law). But in recent years, government
statistics show that increasingly younger officials were caught for corruption.
In 2002, for example, 19.3 percent of the officials prosecuted for bribery were
younger than thirty-five; 29 percent of the officials prosecuted for abuse of
power were younger than thirty-five. This percentage is higher than that of the
CCP officials of the same age group.11 Among the top local officials
and government agency chiefs (the so-called yibashou, or number-one leaders)
caught for corruption in Henan province in 2003, 1,773 (or 43 percent) were
ages forty to fifty, compared with 1,320 (or 32percent) in the
over-fifty age group.12
These two
hypotheses—rising prosperity tends to blunt the pressures for political reform
but also fuels official corruption—are, in fact, consistent with the
developments in China in the 1990s. During that decade, amid unprecedented
economic prosperity, the ruling CCP’s resistance to democratic reform grew more
determined just as official corruption became increasingly virulent.
Theories of
Economic Reform
Economic reform in
countries in the former Soviet bloc, China, and Vietnam has proceeded along two
distinct routes. In the former Soviet bloc, the pace of economic transition was
unusually fast, as was the scope of such transition. Thus, such transitions
have often been characterized as “big bang.”13 In contrast, economic
reform in China and Vietnam has taken a more gradual and deliberate pace, and
the scope of such reform was initially limited. In the literature on economic
and regime transitions in communist systems, whether one approach is superior
to another remains a heated and unsettled controversy.
Proponents of
gradualism maintain that gradual reform has three principal advantages.
LOWER INITIAL
COSTS AND GREATER SUSTAINABILITY: The big-bang approach may create too many
losers at the same time. In addition, a big-bang approach entails enormous
compensation costs, which the government may have no credible means to pay. As
a result, losers from big-bang reforms tend to oppose them fiercely, making
them politically less sustainable. By comparison, gradual reform, through
improving efficiency in certain sectors first, can produce more overall social
benefits. Since the number of losers from partial reform is limited and the
costs of compensation are manageable, the government has greater credibility in
its commitment to compensating the losers, which can enhance the political
sustainability of reform.14
GREATER
FLEXIBILITY: As captured by Deng’s alleged axiom, “crossing the river by
feeling for the stones,” the essence of gradualism is “learning by doing” and
reform through experiments. Reformers may not find the best policy mix, but
they may seek “second-best” solutions that yield immediate efficiency gains.15
Gradualism allows decision makers to target certain sectors for breakthrough
reforms and acquire valuable knowledge for applying reform to other sectors.
Most important, gradualism allows reformers to make—and correct—policy errors
and avoid costly mistakes that can fatally undermine the support for reform.
Over time, market forces can gain strength and become dominant in influencing
decision making and the allocation of resources.16
CONSTITUENCY OF
REFORM: Gradualist reformers can use the classic strategy of divide and rule by
creating beneficiaries of reform first and using them as constituencies for
further reform.17
Gradualism has
many risks, however. First, its record in reforming state-socialist economies
is dismal. In Eastern Europe, the gradualist approach to reform in the 1970s
and 1980s was generally considered a failure. Most scholars of Soviet-style
planned economies argue that only a comprehensive, not a piecemeal, approach
could transform such economies. 18 Second, a gradualist approach
suffers from the lack of complementarity among various reform measures. Some
reform measures that are implemented cannot be fully effective without other
accompanying reforms. János Kornai argues, for example, that implementing some
reforms over others in a piecemeal fashion could backfire and discredit the
entire process of economic liberalization. Initial reforms that are carried out
sluggishly and inconsistently would likely preclude the success of future
reforms.19
The lack of complementarity
can distort markets.20 Gradual or partial reforms also create new
rent-seeking opportunities for the politically connected groups to double-dip
by taking advantage of both the new opportunities offered by the market and the
rents provided by the old unreformed system. These groups typically rely on
their administrative power to create new monopolies and barriers to trade,
resulting in lower output, efficiency losses, and fragmented markets.21
Finally, the
ultimate cconomic costs of transition can be very high if gradualism allows the
ruling elites to make selective withdrawals, initially from sectors with low
rents while holding on to sectors with high rents. Allocation of resources will
remain inefficient. By concealing the information from the public, rulers can
often hide the costs of such gradualist reforms, especially through hidden
public obligations and bad debts in state-controlled banking systems. (Such
concealment is much easier if the country begins the reform with practically no
debt load, as China did in 1979.) China’s approach to reforming state-owned
enterprises is an apt example. The CCP treated SOEs as its last bastion of
rents and patronage, and maintained them on life-support through fiscal
subsidies and bank credits during the reform era. As a result, the allocation
of China’s scarcest resource—capital—was severely distorted. Although SOEs
contributed to only a third of China’s GDP toward the end of the 1990s, they
consumed two-thirds of the domestic investment capital.22 In
addition, two decades of massive subsidies to loss-making SOEs saddled Chinese
public finance with huge hidden obligations.23
Gradualism in
economic reform may be more likely to fail when it is undertaken without
accompanying reforms that restructure the key political institutions that
define power relations and enforce the rules essential to the functioning of
markets, such as security of property rights, transparency of government, and
accountability of leaders. An implicit, but vital, assumption of gradualism is
that reformers are expected to build political coalitions to push for such
institutional changes to safeguard the fruits of economic reform as well as to
sustain its progress. In reality, however, the feasibility of building such
coalitions is rarely assured. This assumption is particularly problematic when
gradualism is undertaken by a regime that possesses overwhelming initial
advantages vis-à-vis societal forces, such as private capital and organized
civic interests. In such a system, proreform coalitions are more likely to
emerge within the regime, rather than between the regime and society, because
either organized societal interests were practically nonexistent after years of
quasi-totalitarian rule or the neoauthoritarian regime does not allow the
emergence of such groups out of fear of their potential threat.
The low
feasibility of forming and sustaining a grand proreform coalition encompassing
both progressive elements inside the regime and organized societal interests
not only increases the uncertainty of gradualist reforms, but also provides the
entrenched interests inside the regime an inherent advantage. Such interests
can always invoke the threat of further reform to the viability of the regime
to block initiatives designed to institutionalize the rules and norms of the
market, further liberalize the economy, and curb the predatory power of the
state. Since reformers within the regime are unable to form alliances with
societal groups—which would benefit from such institutional reforms—they often
experience great difficulty in overcoming such opposition to reform that is
phrased by their opponents in terms of regime survival, rather than economic or
policy rationality. Moreover, antireform elements within the regime can use
private deals to co-opt members of newly influential social groups, such as
private entrepreneurs, thereby creating a government-business collusive network
that makes participation in the antireform coalition far more attractive than
an uncertain alliance with the proreform forces.24
Due to such a
balance of political power, which favors the ruling elites, gradual political
opening under a postcommunist autocratic regime is likely to be highly
uncertain and subject to frequent reversals. In sum, three unfavorable factors
are set against a process of gradual political opening that parallels gradual
economic reform. First, the initial conditions provide the ruling elites an
overwhelming advantage in political organization, patronage, and coercive
power. Second, the process of selective withdrawal creates strong incentives
for the ruling elites to defend their last strongholds of economic and
political privileges. Third, gradualism allows the ruling elites to co-opt new
social elites and form an exclusionary network that divides the opposition,
while creating an incentive structure that rewards cooperation with the
antireform elements and penalizes opposition to such elements.
Gradualism,
Chinese Style
Despite the
potential pitfalls of gradualism, the experience of China’s economic transition
seems to suggest the opposite: gradualism has been a resounding success in
China. In fact, the consensus view has so overwhelmingly endorsed China’s
gradualism that Thomas Rawski claimed in 1999 that “We are all gradualists
now.”25 Such an assessment is mainly based on the consistently high
output growth the country has achieved since it began economic reform in the
late 1970s. Compared with the large fall in output in the transition economics
in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union, China’s rapid output growth
seems to vindicate its gradual approach to economic reform. A leading textbook
on economic transition, which cites the Chinese experience as the most robust
example of the gradualist model, claims that such a model is “more complete and
adequate” than the big-bang approach, otherwise known as the “Washington
consensus.”26 Specifically, economists who have given high marks to
China’s gradualist approach have singled out several key incremental
institutional reforms as reasons for its success in introducing market forces
and incentives without causing disruptions in output.27 One such
reform was the use of dual prices for the same goods; one price was set by the
government and the other determined by market forces. This measure of limited
market liberalization was deemed, economically, “Pareto-improving” and,
politically, palatable to opponents of economic reform. It was “reform without
losers.”28
Another important
example of gradualist institutional innovations cited was the
township-and-village enterprises (TVEs). By Western standards, the property
rights of the TVEs were poorly defined because they were owned by local
governments. Political constraints in China, including both ideological prejudices
against private property and the absence of the rule of law, prevented the
emergence of purely private firms at the initial stage of the transition. Rural
township governments, rather than the central state, managed to overcome these
political constraints and established TVEs that performed more efficiently than
state-owned firms because the interests of the TVE managers and local
politicians were more closely aligned, and because TVEs contributed
significantly to the budgets of township governments.29
In addition,
China’s gradualist approach has had several unique features. First, it has
allowed Chinese leaders fully to exploit the structural advantages provided by
favorable initial conditions. These included a relatively decentralized
economic decision-making system; a political structure conducive to regional
competition; a relatively small proportion of the labor force employed in the
state sector; a less distorted industrial structure compared with the former
Soviet bloc; and a significant nonstate sector.30
Second, Chinese
reformers quickly responded to peasant demands to dismantle the communes and
implemented breakthrough reforms in the country’s most critical economic
sector: agriculture. The initial success of the rural reforms built a crucial
proreform constituency. The surpluses generated by the reform allowed rural
governments to invest in new manufacturing businesses, which eventually became
a critical source of local public finance.31 Thus, while China’s
overall pace of reform may be gradual, its rural reform was decidedly big-bang.
Third, perhaps the
most important feature of China’s approach is the strategy of “growing out of
the plan,” the main thrust of which was to grow a nonstate sector rapidly along
the side of the state sector.32
Unlike the former Soviet bloc countries that experienced sharp falls of output
after adopting the big-bang approach, this strategy allowed China to increase
its output rapidly, thus increasing overall social benefits and generating the
financial means to compensate the losers of reform. More critically, the same
strategy avoided making immediate losers of those groups with entrenched
interests in the state sector (state bureaucracy and workers). This would have
led to a potentially debilitating political battle and undermined support for
reform.
Of course, China’s
gradualist approach has its critics. Some believe that the success of China’s
reform has been overstated, especially given the hidden costs of deteriorating
public finance, the slow pace of structural reform, and the inefficient
allocation of capital.33 Others argue that China’s superior economic
performance during transition is largely due to the country’s structural
factors or initial conditions—such as a less distorted industrial structure,
smaller state subsidies, and a more restrictive state-socialist welfare
system—and not to better policies or institutional innovation.34 In
addition, skeptics believe that economic distortions tend to increase in a
partially reformed economy, citing China’s well-known problem of local
protectionism and the fragmentation of internal markets as examples of massive
economic distortions.35
Implicit in the
arguments presented by the skeptics of China’s gradualist approach is their
belief that gradualism will ultimately fail. They reason that China will
eventually exhaust the advantages generated by its favorable initial
conditions, and the market distortions embedded in an incremental approach will
slow down economic growth. In the absence of constitutional transition (or
democratic transition) in China, the same skeptics worry that the process of
economic transition can be “hijacked by state opportunism” and be exploited by
the ruling elites to consolidate their hold on power, at the expense of the
long-term interests of society.36
The assessment of
China’s economic performance by its own economists shows a surprising degree of
nuance and demonstrates a deep understanding of the benefits and limits of
gradualism. Two themes dominate the discussion by Chinese economists concerning
the country’s reform strategy. First, like their Western counterparts, Chinese
economists clearly recognize the country’s achievement in output growth during
the reform era, and a majority of them share the belief that this gradualist
strategy is a more appropriate approach for China. They point to the rapid
improvement in the standard of living, the pace of industrialization, the
growing links with the world economy, and the increasing influence of market
forces as evidence of the success of the gradualist strategy.37
Second, they also understand the limits of gradualism in transforming the
deeply embedded institutions of a planned economy. In particular, they arc
acutely awarc of the so-called salient systems contradictions—or the constant
frictions and incompatibilities between the emerging market institutions and
the powerful influence of the old system.
To use the blunt
language of an official assessment, “markets in capital, land, technology, and
labor” arc underdeveloped; the government has only “incomplete capabilities in
macroeconomic management” and has failed to “form a system of public finance...
and transform fundamentally the management mechanisms of state-owned
enterprises.” Reform is threatened by the “emergence of special interest groups
within certain government departments and the weakening of the state’s capacity”
and by “the influence of local protectionism.”38 Wu Jinglian argues
that, judged by the changes in the allocation of economic resources, China has
not yet passed its reform test. He believes that the state-owned economy has
not been fundamentally reformed or restructured and that capital is, to a very
large extent, allocated by the government via administrative means.39
Fan Gang, a well-known proponent of gradualism, admits that gradualism carries
huge costs, especially in terms of efficiency losses, continuing price
distortions (due to the controls imposed by the government on key inputs), soft
budget constraints, and monopoly.40
Even the CCP
Central Committee’s assessment of China’s progress in economic reform in late
2003 painted a picture full of difficult challenges ahead. According to the
communiqué of the third plenum of the CCP’s 16th Central Committee, “China’s
economic structure is not rational, the redistributional relationships have not
been smoothed, peasants’ income growth remains slow, contradictions of
employment are growing salient, resource and environmental pressures are
increasing, and the aggregate competitiveness of the Chinese economy is not
strong.”41
The most serious
threat to the viability of China’s gradualist approach, however, is the
weakness of the institutions critical to the functioning of a market economy.
Such institutions include, among other things, a modern legal system and a
constitutional order that can protect private property rights and enforce
contracts, as well as a political system that enforces accountability and
limits state opportunism. A quarter century after China began its transition to
a market economy, these institutions remain relatively underdeveloped. It is
worth noting that, starting in 2001, Wu Jinglian began to emphasize the rule of
law, rather than market forces, as the key to China’s future success. He
publicly declared that, without completing the necessary political reforms,
which would be required to strengthen the institutional foundations of a market
economy, China risked falling into the “trap of crony capitalism.” 42
Reflecting on the evolution of his own thinking, Wu admitted that Chinese
economists like him were naive at the beginning of reform. They thought that
“once the practices of a planned economy were jettisoned and a set of
market-based relationships was established, everything would be smooth-sailing.”
But the problems that emerged twenty-five years into China’s transition cannot
be solved by “pure economics.” “Although a market economy is gradually emerging
in China, problems such as social anomie, rising inequality, and rampant
corruption are getting worse.” Wu concluded that a “good market economy should
be built on the foundations of the rule of law.”43
Why No Autocracy
Has Opted for the Big Bang
The focus on
output growth, incremental institutional change, and the merits and flaws of
the gradualist approach misses a key issue: the connection between an
authoritarian regime and the type of economic strategy it is forced to adopt.
To be sure, most researchers recognize the role played by political constraints
on the course of economic reform. Gérard Roland, for example, identified two
such constraining factors. First, the uncertainty of outcomes, especially in
terms of the distribution of costs and benefits of reform, constrain
policymakers and hamper their ability to build proreform coalitions. Second,
“complementarities and interactions among reforms” also matter because
individual reform measures rarely produce their intended effects without other
complementary measures. In political terms, implementing a reform package
deemed, at least economically, as having a higher degree of complementarity (so
that various components of the reform work better with each other) may actually
undermine reformers. Such a package can hurt more entrenched interests and, at
the same time, galvanize their opposition to change.44 Implicit in
the complementarity constraint is the assumption that this type of constraint
forces reformers to adopt a gradualist or incremental approach to divide and
conquer the opposition.
Proponents of
gradualism seem to have overlooked the greatest political constraint on
economic reform: an authoritarian regime’s fear of losing power during reform
most likely far outweighs its worries about encountering opposition to such
reform. The most important political logic that drives economic reform under
autocracy is not one based on a Machiavellian calculation of
coalition-building, but one that is centered on regime survival. According to
this perspective, authoritarian regimes facing the choice between reform and a
crisis-ridden status quo—as was the case in the immediate aftermath of the
Cultural Revolution in China—must choose between two unpalatable options.
Maintaining a deteriorating status quo will most likely threaten the regime’s
survival both in the short term and for the long run.
However, to the
extent that complete market-oriented reforms will eventually deprive the regime
of the resources it needs to buy support from interest groups, an authoritarian
regime’s long-term survival will also be at risk—even though its short-term
prospects may brighten as a result of economic reform. In addition to
status-quo bias, which threatens regime survival, and gradualist reform, which
increases risks to the regime’s long-term survival should it truly succeed,
there is a third threat: a big-bang reform.45 A big-bang approach
may not only mobilize opposition from various quarters simultaneously, but it
could also force the authoritarian regime to relinquish its control over vital
economic resources so quickly that it would also lose its grip on political
power.
This is why all
authoritarian regimes in history, including the most promarket Pinochet regime
in Chile, have shunned the big-bang approach to economic reform.46
Instead, all authoritarian regimes that have been forced to undertake economic
reform have opted for the gradualist strategy, with the state maintaining tight
control in vital sectors (Vietnam in the 1990s, Indonesia under Suharto, Taiwan
under the Kuomintang, South Korea in the 1960s, and Mexico under the PRI
[revolutionary party]). Revealingly, the big-bang approach was embraced only in
those countries where the authoritarian regimes had been overthrown, including
the former communist regimes in Eastern Europe that had tried various forms of
gradualism before.
What makes
gradualism a favored strategy for authoritarian regimes embarking on economic
reform? The political logic of gradualism is both compelling and
straightforward. Few authoritarian regimes can rely on coercion alone to
maintain power. Most autocracies mix coercion with patronage to secure support
from key constituencies, such as the bureaucracy, the military, and business
groups. In the Chinese case, for example, the state controlled more than
260,000 enterprises, with total assets valued at 16.7 trillion yuan in 2001 (or
177 percent of GDP).47 The patronage that the control of these
assets can underwrite is the key to the CCP’s survival. The centerpiece of such
a vast patronage system is the regime’s ability to secure the loyalty of
supporters and allocate rents to favored groups. The CCP appoints 81 percent of
the managers of SOEs and 56 percent of all enterprise managers.
The corporate
governance reforms implemented since the late 1990s did little to change this
patronage system. In the restructured large and medium-sized SOEs—which were
ostensibly transformed into share-holding companies—the party secretaries and
the chairmen of the board were the same person in about half the firms. In the
6,275 large and medium-sized SOEs that had been classified as restructured as
of 2001, the party committee members of the prerestructured firms became the
board of directors in 70 percent of the restructured firms. Altogether, the CCP
had 5.3 million officials—about 8 percent of its total membership and 16
percent of its urban members—who held executive positions in SOEs in 2003.48
To the extent that
a big-bang strategy reduces economic distortion and hence an authoritarian
regime’s ability to create and allocate rents, that regime’s ability to retain
political support will be undermined drastically. Under the logic of political
survival, the advantages of gradualism appear self-evident to authoritarian
regimes. Unlike the big bang, gradualism allows the ruling elites to protect
their rents in vital sectors and use retained rents to maintain political
support among key constituencies. Under gradualism, the regime is assured of
its ability to decide where it wants to surrender rents and to whom such rents
will be given. Retaining this ability is of paramount political importance. If
a regime can choose the sectors to liberalize, the same political logic
dictates that it should first liberalize sectors where rents are relatively low
and less concentrated. Giving up low-rent sectors means that the regime
suffers, at most, minor loss of patronage. Liberalizing sectors in which rents
are not highly concentrated is unlikely to encounter determined opposition. In
the Chinese case, reforms in agriculture, consumer retail, and light industry
fit this logic very well.
It is a more
tricky issue to decide to whom the regime should turn over the rents from these
liberalized areas, if we assume partial reform and residual rents in these
sectors, as is often the case. It is possible that, once liberalizing reforms
are implemented fully, rents may disappear completely. As a result, rent
reallocation is no longer an issue. But as residual rents are a common feature
of transition economies, an authoritarian regime engaged in economic reform
must decide which groups should have access to the residual rents. Again, based
on the political logic of survival, authoritarian regimes tend to favor
nonthreatening groups and groups that can be co-opted. Foreign investors, for
example, can be a nonthreatening group because their primary motive is profit,
not power. Domestic private entrepreneurs, however, may pose more direct
long-term threats.
That is perhaps
why, as of 2003, indigenous private Chinese firms still faced high, if not
impossible, barriers to entering about thirty sectors, such as banking,
insurance, securities, telecommunication services, petro-chemicals,
automobiles, and other industries deemed critical by the government.49
In contrast, the Chinese government welcomed foreign firms to enter many of the
same industrial sectors. China has favored foreign investors not solely because
they can supply capital and technology, but also because of the CCP’s fear of
domestic private capital. 50 Indeed, as Yasheng Huang’s
groundbreaking research shows, foreign direct investment surged into China
mainly thanks to the Chinese state’s discrimination against domestic private
firms.51
The regime’s
ability to protect and reallocate rents under gradualism allows the ruling
elites to retain the resources to co-opt new social elites and groups that may
threaten their authority. Under gradualism, market reforms tend to be
incremental and create imperfect competition in the interim. Because of this,
the government maintains significant residual control even in areas where
liberalization has already taken place. The ruling elites can parcel out the
residual rents in these areas to new groups targeted for co-optation.
Politically, such co-optations can help shore up the social base of support for
the regime even as it alienates its traditional allies. In the Chinese case,
gradualism has apparently generated political dividends not only in
growth-enhanced legitimacy, but also in the CCP’s success in co-opting emerging
private entrepreneurs and a large segment of the new urban middle class, such
as professionals and select members of the intelligentsia who have been
recruited into the government.52
However,
gradualism ultimately becomes untenable because of rent dissipation by
insiders. At the aggregate level, an authoritarian regime that is successful in
protecting the major sources of its rent should be able to extend its
longevity. It can use the rent to maintain its base of support, provided that
it keeps rent dissipation by insiders at a manageable level. But both theory
and experience show that rent protection and dissipation go together. Few
regimes are capable of protecting their rents for long, while preventing their
insiders from dissipating the same rents. In a transitional environment marked
by high uncertainty for the members of the ruling elites, weak enforcement of
rules, and low accountability, rent dissipation by insiders is likely to
increase because insiders have both the means (monopolistic political power) to
appropriate the rent to themselves and the motivations to do so (fear of an
uncertain future).
The combined
effect of rent protection and dissipation is the coexistence of aggregate
inefficiency, financial deterioration, and insider corruption, as illustrated
by the three case studies in Chapter 3. In other words, a self-destructive
logic is embedded in a gradualist reform strategy adopted by an authoritarian
regime obsessed with survival. As proponents of gradualism have argued, such a
strategy may make a lot of sense, especially given the historical contexts
marking the transition to a market economy in former socialist countries. Such
a strategy assumes, however, that agent opportunism will be held in check,
although literature on gradualism has not specified how. In reality, agent
opportunism—the main reason for rent dissipation by insiders—is a common
problem in transition economies. In the context of gradualism under autocratic
rule, state or regime opportunism further encourages agent opportunism as the
policies of the authoritarian regime provide its agents with the chances to
appropriate rents. Because the authoritarian regime relies on the same agents
to maintain its power, it becomes almost powerless in combating agent
opportunism and containing rent dissipation.