Excerpt from China’s Trapped Transition - The Limits of
Developmental Autocracy by Minxin Pei
A
Question of the State: Developmental or Predatory
The sustained
economic development achieved under authoritarian rule in Singapore, Taiwan,
Hong Kong, and South Korea from the 1960s to 1980s has provided the factual
basis for the claim that a neoauthoritarian mode of development—state-guided
rapid economic growth under authoritarian rule—is a superior and proven strategy.53
To be sure, in the Western academic community, the concept of an East Asian
model is a subject of debate, especially because of the controversy over the
efficacy and degree of state intervention in East Asian countries. For some
scholars, the East Asian experience is proof of the centrality of state
intervention in the rapid growth of late-developers.54 For others,
right public policies were the key to East Asian success.55
Unfortunately,
most leading scholars of East Asian political economy have skirted the issue of
regime and development. Only Robert Wade, author of one of the most influential
studies on the role of the state in East Asia’s economic development, explicitly
identified the development “of effective institutions of political authority
before the system is democratized” as a key to East Asia’s success.56
Within the Chinese political and intellectual elite, the East Asian model has
been essentially reduced to a simple formula: strong government authority +
promarket policies = superior economic performance. It has further been argued
that strong government authority would be difficult to obtain under democratic
political systems.57 In fact, when asked about his views on
neoauthoritarianism by Zhao Ziyang in a private conversation in 1988, Deng
admitted that such a strategy, “relying on a political strongman to maintain
stability and develop the economy,” was exactly what he was advocating even
though “it is not necessary to use the term (neoauthoritarianism).”58
Such a
preoccupation with the efficacy of the state in the context of economic
development overlooks one crucial issue: the relationship between economic
growth and the predatory behavior of the state. In other words, the real East
Asian puzzle is not how sustained rapid economic development occurred under
strong states, but why and how the predatory, practices of the state were held
in check. Based on the assumption of the state as a “helping hand,” much of the
literature on the political economy of development in East Asia has all but
ignored the possibility that a strong state can also be a “grabbing hand.”59
Peter Evans’s influential Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation
may be the only exception. By identifying the nature of the state as the
critical variable in explaining the variations in the success of
industrialization in developing countries, Evans shows that a predatory state
is incapable of nurturing new engines of growth (in his case, the information
industry).60
But Evans’s
explanation of why some states are nurturers while others are predators
addresses only part of the puzzle. His formulation of the “embedded autonomy”
of the state—the idea that developmental states gain autonomy and efficacy only
when they arc “immersed in a dense network of ties that bind them to societal
allies with transformational goals”—provides a useful answer, but appears to
restate the well-known: states counterbalanced by strong societal coalitions
are less likely to be predatory.61 Such explanations, built on the
perspective of state-society relations, fail to probe the internal
organizational dynamics and norms of the state. While few would deny the
desirability and benefits of having strong societal forces committed to
economic development, the most important challenge in the real world is that,
in the overwhelming majority of developing countries, such forces are extremely
weak or absent altogether. The transformativc project has to begin inside the
state.
Yet, there is
another conundrum: as some scholars have argued, no evidence exists to show
that institutions can be devised to make the state an effective protector of
property rights, but at the same time prevent it from abusing its power. In
other words, there is no guarantee that the same helping hand will not become a
grabbing hand.62
Indeed, as the
experience of most developing countries shows, states as helping hands are the
exception. Sustained developmental successes probably number fewer than ten,
with most of them concentrated in the East Asian region.63 At the
same time, predatory states have caused disastrous failures in a majority of
poor countries, the most egregious examples being the Philippines under Marcos,
Zaire under Mobutu, and Haiti under the Duvaliers. As the collapse of the
Indonesian economy in 1997-1998 demonstrates, without adequate institutional
controls imposed on predatory states, even initial successes could end up as
catastrophic failures.
The Theory of the
Predatory State
In its simplest
formulation, the theory of the predatory state is based on a conception of the
state as a grabbing hand. It envisions the central role of the state as the
expropriation of wealth from society through taxes for the preservation of the
state’s own power.64 The recent growing appeal of the theory is due,
in large part, to the application of the institutionalist approach to the
research on the relationship between political institutions and economic
performance.65 The revival of institutionalism has again elevated
the role of the state in economic development.66
To be sure, the
institutionalist perspective on the state differs from that of the
developmental state, which, as popularized by scholars of East Asia, has a
direct role in correcting market failures. Institutionalists see the state as
the provider and enforcer of rules and norms that underpin market transactions.
This distinction is significant because the perspectives on the state behind it
are fundamentally different. Unlike the helping hand envisioned in the
developmental state perspective, the state is seen by institutionalists as a
force both for good and evil. As Douglass North puts it, “The existence of a
state is essential for economic growth; the state, however, is the source of
man-made economic decline.”67 Although the state may be a helping
hand that specifies and protects efficient property rights, it can also be a
grabbing hand that expropriates the wealth of its people.68
The grabbing-hand
perspective appeals to students of development because the theory of the
predatory state provides a persuasive explanation for the weakness of the state
and the overall poor performance of government. In applying this perspective,
however, we need to make the distinction between centralized predation and
decentralized predation because such a distinction is crucial to understanding
the different dynamics behind a state’s institutional performance. In the
earlier formulations of the theory of the predatory state, the focus is on the
aggregate level of state predation and treats predation as the political
imperative of the ruler. There is no distinction between the principal and the
agent. As a result, predation is conceived as an act of the principal. This
formulation assumes, first, that state predation is universal. Because rulers
are monopolists of both violence and public goods, state predation, in the form
of taxes, is simply the price private producers of wealth pay for such
monopolistic services. Second, the most important factor that limits the level
of a ruler’s predation is his self-interest. To use Mancur Olson’s colorful
analogy, a self-interested ruler behaves like a “stationary bandit” who is
unlikely to risk his future revenue streams by looting the current stock of
wealth of his subjects. He will raise taxation only up to the level that
maximizes his tax revenues.69 Third, rulers are supposed to have an
encompassing interest that is akin to the national interest.
In both theory and
practice, centralized predation can spiral out of control. The ruler’s
encompassing interest may diverge fundamentally from that of the state. For
example, the ruler’s personal greed may become insatiable. He and his close
cronies may loot wealth, not to provide public goods, but to line their own pockets,
thus creating a kleptocracy. 70 The ruler’s encompassing interest
may also become too ambitious for his nation’s good. Desire to acquire a larger
territory (hence tax base) or international prestige may motivate the ruler to
extract excessively from society to build a strong military.71 In
addition, the ruler’s monopolistic position is always insecure because a
domestic or foreign rival can seize his monopoly by force.72 This
structural insecurity affects the ruler’s time horizon and the rate of discount
on future revenues, incentivizing behaviors that result in short-term gains but
long-term revenue losses.73
Finally, the absence of a third-party enforcer makes the ruler’s commitment to
self-restrained predation not credible. Temptations for the ruler to break his
promise and increase predation always exist, and most rulers have honored their
promises in the breach.74
In the theoretical
literature on decentralized predation, the emphasis is on predation by agents
of the state. Although agency costs have been identified as a constraint on the
ruler’s ability to maintain a desired level of extraction, the effects of such
costs on state predation have not been explored until recently.75
Scholars who focus on the role of agents in state predation see decentralized
predation as more harmful to the interest of the state. Andrei Shleifer and
Robert Vishny demonstrate that centralized corruption, which is a form of
monopolist predation, generates higher aggregate revenue for the state—because
the state keeps its rate of extraction at the optimal level—than decentralized
corruption (a form of predation by state agents acting as independent
monopolists), which not only raises the overall level of theft (that is, making
corruption more widespread), but also reduces the aggregate amount of income
for the state. Since predatory agents simultaneously compete with one another
for the same revenue, they have the incentive to steal everything, behaving
essentially like Olson’s “roving bandits.”76 The welfare loss from
decentralized predation is much greater than that from centralized predation.77
Decentralized predation, moreover, has emerged as a more prevalent problem
today, as regime transition in many countries has restructured some of the key
institutions governing principal-agent relations (more on the effects of
transition on decentralized predation below).
To be sure, the
relationship between centralization and corruption is a subject of scholarly
dispute. Some scholars believe that decentralization may actually reduce the
level of corruption. For example, decentralization can make local officials
more accountable to the public because they can no longer hide behind the
actions taken by higher authorities. Greater political accountability would
help control corruption. 78 Decentralization may also contribute to
lower levels of corruption because local officials are deterred from corrupt
activities by a higher likelihood of being caught. Moreover, decentralization
deprives the central government of the financial resources that otherwise are
routinely squandered on grand corruption schemes (such as white elephant
projects), thus reducing the aggregate costs of corruption. Even though
decentralization can lead to a short-term increase of petty corruption by local
officials, the total costs of petty corruption are likely to be much lower.79
Many scholars
believe, however, that decentralization can increase corruption for several
reasons.
Given the low wages paid to local officials, increased political
discretion as a result of decentralization is likely to lead to more
corruption.80 If decentralization should lead to the breaking of
arm’s-length relationships between clients and government agents, it can cause
corruption to rise, especially in cultures where interpersonal connections play
an important role. Newly empowered local bureaucrats are thus more likely to
reward family friends with various forms of rents.81
Decentralization may exacerbate corruption if it occurs in the context of weak
government. When the political authority of the government is weak across the
board, decentralization can create independent monopolists who have every
incentive to maximize the collection of bribery at the local level.82
On balance, the argument that decentralization can lead to more corruption is
more persuasive because its proponents adequately account for the agency
problem, while the same problem is simply assumed away by those who believe
that decentralization can reduce corruption.83
The distinction
between centralized and decentralized predation notwithstanding, the central
point of the predatory state perspective is self-evident : without effective
political institutions or structural constraints that curb the predatory
appetite of the state, a state that is sufficiently strong to promote economic
development unhindered by parochial interests is also strong enough to prey
upon society without much restraint. The consequences of unrestrained state
predation are dire. In such a state, the ruling elites distort markets, create
rent-seeking opportunities for self-enrichment, and loot the wealth of society.
Sustained economic development under such a state is impossible. The hope that
economic development would eventually lead to democratic transition is only
wishful thinking because the predatory state and economic development are,
logically, mutually exclusive.
Why Decentralized
Predation May Emerge during Transition
Research on
transitions in the former socialist states indicates a significant increase in
decentralized predation immediately following regime changes. Joel Hellman’s
study of reform in the former Soviet bloc countries suggested that the ruling
elites were able to capture the state and reap all the benefits of partial
economic reforms.84 Michael McFaul and Federico Varese found that
the communist ruling elites in the former Soviet Union were able to use their
institutional privileges and exploit the loopholes in property rights laws to
steal public assets in the privatization process.85 In an insightful
analysis of the collapse of the former Soviet Union, Steven Solnick showed that
transitions that decentralize authority tend to lead to an increase in the
number of thefts of state assets.86
Theoretically, the
type of post-transition state predation observed by country specialists and
journalists is qualitatively different from that which occurred during the
pre-transition era. In pre-transition communist countries, state predation was
centralized. Two characteristics defined centralized predation under communist
rule. First, the aggregate amount of revenues generated was large, reflected in
the government revenue as a share of GDP. Second, a significant amount of the
revenues was used to provide public goods, mainly national defense, health, and
education spending. Consequently, countries ruled by communist regimes enjoyed
a higher level of human development relative to their economic development,
especially in terms of their literacy rate, infant mortality rate, and life
expectancy.87
By contrast,
posttransition state predation is decentralized and manifests itself in various
forms of official corruption. Decentralized state predation reduces the
aggregate amount of state revenue, as agents divert public money into private
pockets. It also causes a fall in the provision of public goods, as state agents
convert public resources into private consumption or offshore investments.
Although the phenomenon of decentralized state predation in post-transition
countries has received enormous attention, the causes of decentralized
predation are not well understood.
Centralized
predation becomes decentralized when the state, as the principal, loses
effective control over its agents. Of course, different types of regime
transitions generate different dynamics that affect principal-agent relations.
In communist states that saw a quick collapse of the ancien regime, state
agents were afforded great advantages by even the temporary decline of the
principal’s authority. In those societies, the agents’ theft of state assets
was completed within a relatively short period of time. However, the patterns
of post-transition agent predation diverged dramatically in those
post-communist states that experienced dual transition. As Hellman’s work
shows, new regimes with a higher degree of democracy and more complete market reforms
tend to restrain such predation, while new regimes with less democracy and
partial economic reforms are beset by increased levels of agent-predation.88
By comparison,
agent-predation followed a different dynamic in post-communist systems that
have seen market liberalization but no political transition, such as in China
and Vietnam. In these societies, the political authority of the state remains
unchallenged. However, the decentralization of decision making, needed to
reincentivize state agents, led to a restructuring of the contracts between the
state and its agents, which proved to be extremely advantageous to the latter.
Therefore, the key to understanding the rise of decentralized predation is to
examine both the preexisting and the transition-related institutional changes
that have structured and restructured principal-agent relations. Specifically,
changes in the control of property rights, mechanisms of monitoring, exit
options, and institutional norms arc the critical variables responsible for the
decentralization of state predation in postcommunist societies.
Decentralization
of property rights
In theory, the
degree of centralization of property rights is negatively correlated with
decentralized predation. In countries with a high level of centralization of
property rights, the loss of state money through agent theft or
misappropriation tends to be small. Under the prereform communist system,
despite the lack of clarity of property rights, the high degree of
centralization of such rights was the decisive institutional factor that
limited agent-predation. In practice, the centralization of property rights
prevented large-scale theft of state property. Of course, the mono-property
rights regime and the high degree of centralization of property rights caused
low efficiency because this system provided few incentives for agents to
improve the financial performance of state assets.89 The
decentralization of property rights during the transition phase in most
state-socialist systems was originally designed to increase agent incentives so
that state assets could become more productive. In some countries, such as
China, the decentralization of property rights also involved the transfer of
formal ownership of state assets from the central government to local
governments. Such decentralization granted the state’s managerial agents more
discretion in operating SOEs, especially regarding investment and compensation.
Although no evidence shows that decentralization of property rights alone
contributes to efficiency gains, the combination of lack of clarity of property
rightsand decentralization of such rights has led to widespread asset-stripping
and other forms of theft by state agents.90
Ineffective
monitoring
Given the
institutional changes entailed in regime transition, the old system of
monitoring state agents is likely to break down. Rule changes are frequent and
confusing during transition, resulting in poor coordination among various state
agencies monitoring agent behavior, such as the secret police, tax authorities,
auditors, and financial controllers. The breakdown of monitoring becomes even
more likely if those state agents in charge of monitoring other state agents
detect the latter’s theft but decide to divide the spoils with the thieving
agents, instead of reporting their malfeasance to the principal.
(Unsurprisingly, one of the most corrupt government bureaucracies in China and
Russia is the anticorruption agency.) Transition frequently entails changes in
political values and erodes the authority of the principal. Agents face
negligible risks in defying the authority of the principal. Erosion of the
principal’s authority makes effective monitoring of agents ineffective. The
monitoring of agents has also become more difficult under reform because of an
increase in transaction channels. As X. L. Ding observed, interfirm
transactions almost did not exist under the old system, in which ministries
directly controlled SOEs’ sales and purchase processes. As a result, the
monitoring of agents’ business deals was easier under the old system. In the
transition era, the advent of marketization replaced the firm-ministry-firm
transactions chain with the more efficient firm-to-firm transactions chain.
Consequently, the number of transactions exploded, making effective government
monitoring nearly impossible.91
New exit options
Large-scale theft
of state assets was made less likely under the old communist system by the absence
of exit options from the state sector for nearly all agents. Regime transition
has opened numerous exits for these agents, including ownership stakes and
managerial positions in the new private or semiprivate firms, and overseas
investment opportunities. 92 These exits effectively allowed
“stationary bandits” under the old system to become “roving bandits” because
they can steal and then store their loot safely elsewhere. The time horizon of
state agents with lucrative exit options is likely to be short, resulting in
more intense theft of state assets.
Erosion of
institutional norms
Institutionalists
have long recognized the role of institutional norms in constraining agent
opportunism and the free-rider problem.93 As a concept,
institutional norms are vague and difficult to define. In practice,
institutional norms may derive much of their legitimacy, appeal, and binding
power from the prevailing ideology of the political system. In the case of
communist systems, it may be controversial to claim that the communist ideology
had any appeal. One can point to the widespread cynicism among the ruling
elites of the ancien régime. It is nevertheless conceivable that even residual
ideological appeals of communism, socialism, or nationalism might have played a
role in constraining the predatory instincts of the agents under the old
regime. During transition, the total bankruptcy of the communist ideology meant
that state agents were under no constraints imposed by institutional norms.
The above
theoretical analysis suggests that a temporary partial reform equilibrium, or a
transition trapped in semireformed economic and political institutions, is a
product of a confluence of factors. The most important among them includes the initial
conditions of the transition process in post-totalitarian regimes such as the
CCP, which retains unchallenged political supremacy over society and maintains
its rule through a mixture of coercion, co-optation, and adaptation. Additional
factors contributing to the emergence of such a trap are embedded in the
political and economic logic of market transitions and authoritarian politics.
Indeed, the Chinese experience provides an intriguing example that demonstrates
why gradualist economic reform pursued under a neoauthoritarian regime, even
after achieving impressive initial results, may lose momentum. Instead of
moving toward an even more open economy and society, such a system may be
heading toward long-term stagnation amid widespread symptoms of state
incapacitation and deterioration of governance.
At the theoretical
level, one can construct an argument that incorporates the insights from the
theories of democratization, economic reform, and predatory state to explain
the phenomenon of trapped transitions.
Gradual democratic
transitions in post-totalitarian regimes face higher hurdles than those in
authoritarian regimes. The connection between economic development and
political liberalization is likely to be weak in these regimes because the
initial conditions are far more adverse. The institutionalized curbs on the
power of the ruling elites in a post-totalitarian regime are negligible. The
ruling elites thus have far greater ability to defeat societal challenges. The
presence of the post-totalitarian ruling party in state bureaucracies, economic
entities, the military, and the judiciary provides it with the instant ability
to convert political monopoly into economic rents during economic transition.
Consequently, economic growth, rather than creating exits for peaceful
withdrawal from power and lowering the costs of political transition, may
perversely increase the stakes of exiting power because the ruling elites risk
losing not only political power, but also economic rents. In addition, such
rents become more valuable in an open and fast-growing economy, and, more
important, the material wealth accurnulated by the ruling elites can be
consumed openly, extravagantly, and without fear when the prereform codes of
austerity are no longer operative. Therefore, even though economic growth may
have a long-run positive impact on democratization, its short-run impact can be
decidedly negative.
Gradualist
transitions can further help entrench the post-totalitarian party-state and
thwart efforts to both deepen market reforms and initiate democratic
transition. Gradualism allows the ruling elites to make selective withdrawals
and maintain their control in the most lucrative high-rent sectors; this
development tends to make the ruling elites even less inclined to give up
political power during transition. The control over sectors with rich rents
also facilitates the emergence of -political alliances with stakes in a
semireformed system but with no interest in political reform, as the ruling
elites use such control to co-opt emerging social elites individually, include
them in a collusive network of rent-sharing, and preempt potential political
challengers. To the extent that initial reform efforts may be successful,
gradualist reforms buy the regime a new, albeit temporary, lease on life,
removing the pressures for political reform. Gradualism becomes eventually
unsustainable because of the problem of dissipation of rents. The regime’s
strategy of protecting rents in key sectors ultimately fails when such rents
are distributed and consumed by the agents of the regime, critically weakening
the health of the economy.
However appealing
the concept of a developmental state, successful economic development under
neoauthoritarianism may be the exception. A self-restrained developmental state
can materialize only under rare circumstances that force the ruling elites to
choose between curbing their predatory appetite or risking their own survival,
a choice that is not always correctly made. In post-totalitarian political systems
where the ruling elites possess overwhelming advantages vis-à-vis societal
oppositions, operate under ineffective institutional restraints on their power,
and face no credible external threat, the state is most likely a grabbing hand,
not a helping hand. Thus, despite its promarket rhetoric and policies, a
post-totalitarian regime may likely degenerate into a predatory autocracy,
rather than evolve into a developmental neoautocracy. Economic development
under a predatory autocracy is ultimately unsustainable. Ironically, a
democratic opening may emerge in the end, not as a regime-initiated strategy
undertaken at its own choosing, but more likely as the result of a sudden
crisis brought on by years of corruption, mismanagement, and institutional
decay.